5 Mitchell Street, Edinburgh, Scotland
info@katalatto.org

Katalatto Asks: Why Property Rights are important to unlock trillions in dead capital?

Katalatto Asks: Why Property Rights are important to unlock trillions in dead capital?

Hernando de Soto is a big name in development economics. His energetic opposition to Peru’s Maoist guerrilla group, the Shining Path, led to three assassination attempts. His big idea is to make sure that the legal system can see as much as the dogs of Bali. While the Indonesian government was trying to formalise property rights, others have tried to abolish them altogether.

Hernando de Soto argues better property rights could make a big difference to the world’s poor on his so-called book “The Mystery of Capital”

About two billion people have full rights to the property they live in and the land they farm. For the 5.3 billion who do not have such rights, the implications are stark: people are unable to leverage their resources to create wealth, and their assets become “dead capital” which cannot be used to generate income or growth. As a result, the poor remain trapped by the “tragedy of the commons” where their unregistered assets can be stolen by powerful interests, hurting individuals and broader economic development according to de Soto.

Daring plan

In 1970s China, for example, where the Maoists weren’t the rebels but the government, the very idea that anyone could own anything was seditious, bourgeois thinking.
Farmers on collective farms were told by Communist Party officials that they didn’t own a thing. Everything belonged to the collective.What about the teeth in my head, asked one farmer? As noted by NPR’s Planet Money podcast, he was told that even his teeth were owned by the collective. The land, its produce – and even the workers’ teeth – belonged to the collective in 1970s China.
This approach worked terribly: if you don’t own anything, why bother to look after it? Avoiding toothache is an incentive to brush your teeth. But collective ownership of land left farmers in desperate, gnawing poverty. So, in Xiaogang in 1978, a group of farmers secretly met and agreed a daring plan.

 

Conspicuous success

Instead of farming as a collective, they would informally divide up the land, and each keep whatever surplus they produced after meeting collective quotas. It was a treasonous agreement in Communist eyes: discovery risked execution.
In fact, they were found out thanks to their conspicuous success: their farms produced more in one year than in the previous five years combined. But luck was on their side.
Deng Xiaoping, who became leader in 1978, laid the foundations for China’s modern economy.
China now had a new leader: Deng Xiaoping. And Deng let it be known that this was the sort of experiment that had his blessing. And 1978 was the beginning of China’s breakneck transformation from utter poverty to, by some measures, the largest economy on the planet.

Invisible web

The experience in China shows that even informal property rights can be incredibly powerful.
If you know your neighbours respect your boundaries, you can feel confident investing time in weeding your vegetable plot, or building a house.
But in one critical way, it doesn’t help me that my neighbours agree that I own my house. If I want a loan – to improve my house, or build a business – lenders need collateral. And land or buildings make particularly good collateral because they tend to increase in value, and it’s hard to hide them from creditors. Banks will lend against property only if its ownership can be proven in law. But the lender needs to be confident it could take the house away from me if I don’t repay the loan. So, I need to prove that the house really is mine. That requires an invisible web of information that the legal system and the banking system can use.
For Hernando de Soto, this invisible web is the difference between my house being an asset – something useful that I own – and being capital – an asset recognised by the financial system.

‘Dead capital’

In poor countries, a lot of assets are informally held. Hernando de Soto calls them “dead capital”, useless for securing a loan. His estimate was that at the start of the 21st Century there was almost $10tn  worth of dead capital across the developing world – more than $4,000  for every person.
Other researchers think that’s an overestimate and the true figure is probably $3tn  or $4tn, but either way, it’s a huge amount. But how do assets become capital? How does the invisible web get woven? It needs a government.

Enforcing property rights is one of the few things pretty much everyone on the political spectrum agrees a government should do, except perhaps the Maoists.
It’s not just an altruistic measure to make it easier to get a mortgage. When government knows who owns land, it can tax it however.

Napoleonic ‘cadastres’

Perhaps the first recognisably modern property registry was in Napoleonic France. Needing to fund his incessant wars, Napoleon decreed that all French properties would be carefully mapped, and their ownership registered. Napoleon decreed that all properties in the territories he controlled would be mapped and registered Such a property map is called a “cadastre”, and Napoleon proudly proclaimed that “a good cadastre of the parcels will be the complement of my civil code”. After conquering Switzerland, the Netherlands and Belgium, Napoleon introduced cadastral maps there, as well.

Bold pioneers

In the mid-1800s, the idea of the land registry spread quickly through the British Empire, too. The government drew up maps and allocated title deeds. Of course at that time, nobody with any power had much interest in the fact that indigenous people had their own claims on the land.
The process doesn’t have to be top-down. In the United States, there was a bottom-up approach. After decades of treating squatters as criminals, the state began to think of them as bold pioneers.
The 1862 Homestead Act set out the rules on who could own land in the US’s western territories.
The US government tried to formalise informal property claims, using the Preemption Act of 1841 and the Homestead Act of 1862. Again, the rights of the native people who had been living there for thousands of years were not regarded as of much significance.
It was hardly justice. But it was profitable. By turning a land-grab into a legally recognised property right, these land registries unlocked decades of investment and improvement.

And some economists – most prominently Hernando de Soto himself – argue that a good way to create property registers for developing countries today is to use the same bottom-up process of recognising informal squatters’ rights, coupled with modern databases.
Do improved property registers really unlock what Hernando de Soto calls “dead capital”?
Evidently, they can. In Ghana, for example, farmers with clearer property rights invested more in their land.

Essential infrastructure

But the answer, of course, is “it depends”. It depends on whether there’s a banking system capable of lending, and an economy worth borrowing money to invest in. The Philippines’ labyrinthine property registration system involves 168 steps. And it depends on how smoothly the property register works. Hernando de Soto found that in the Philippines, legally registering property took 168 procedures, 53 agencies and a waiting list of 13 to 25 years. Faced with such obstacles, even formally registered properties are likely to become informal again – the next time the property is traded, both the buyer and the seller may decide that formalising the deal is just too time consuming.
But get it right, and the results can be impressive.
Providing the world’s poor with titles for their land, homes and unregistered businesses would unlock $9.3 trillion in assets, de Soto estimates, an unprecedented sum to reduce poverty.

The World Bank has found that after controlling for income and economic growth, the countries with simpler, quicker property registries also had less corruption, less grey-market activity, more credit and more private investment.

 

 

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *